The two narratives about the COVID-19 pandemic continue to clash as evidence mounts about the actual outcomes of the extraordinary strategies governments deployed to try and contain the epidemic. Has the emerging evidence vindicated the decisions governments have been making over the past three years? In particular, were they ethically justified in imposing harsh mandates on their populations?
At the outset, of course, there was actually no evidence that lockdowns would work – zero. Because they had never been tried before, there was no accumulated knowledge to go on.
There was only theory and modelling, and it is important to stress that modelling is not empirical evidence.
And even the initial modelling did not show that universal lockdowns were the preferable strategy. As I have pointed out before, Neil Ferguson’s infamous ‘Report Nine’ actually shows the lowest epidemic curve resulting from a mix of measures including confinement only for the over 70s.
Interestingly, a team from the University of Edinburgh has run a version of the same model, with some modifications (especially, “We also count deaths in all waves, not just the first”) and arrived at similar conclusions. Table Three in their report summarises counterintuitive findings, including that:
…adding school closures to a scenario with case isolation, household quarantine, and social distancing in people older than 70 years would increase the total number of deaths across the full simulation. Moreover, it shows that social distancing in those over 70 would be more effective than general social distancing.
Then they went further, and found that:
Stronger interventions… are associated with suppression of the infection such that a second wave is observed once the interventions are lifted:
When the interventions are lifted, there is still a large population who are susceptible and a substantial number of people who are infected. This then leads to a second wave of infections that can result in more deaths, but later. Further lockdowns would lead to a repeating series of waves of infection unless herd immunity is achieved by vaccination, which is not considered in the model.
In summary: “Postponing the spread of COVID-19 means that more people are still infectious and are available to infect older age groups, of whom a much larger fraction then die.” This is represented in their Figure One, in which the first five scenarios are the same ones presented by Ferguson’s Report Nine, with another three scenarios showing the second (or later) wave scenarios with either general social distancing or social distancing for the over-70s.

Key: ICU=intensive care unit; PC=place closures; CI=case isolation; HQ=household quarantine; SDOL70=social distancing of over 70s; SD=general social distancing.
None of this modelling might be reliable (see below), but the point is: the same model that launched the lockdowns also indicates that the medium-term outcomes might be unfavourable, so experimenting with lockdowns was a dangerous experiment, a leap in the dark. Governments had no idea whether the emergency measures would increase or decrease even COVID-19 mortality, let alone mortality overall, in the medium term.
This is serious, as evidence of the ‘collateral damage’ or adverse effects from lockdowns has been mounting.
The World Bank estimated that the combined effects of the pandemic itself and lockdowns led to 97 million more people being in poverty in 2020 than the previous year. It is likely that most of these adverse effects derived from the lockdowns, as the poorer countries predominantly have a younger population that are less susceptible to the disease. They were made to endure harsh interventions that were not remotely justifiable given their lower risk profile.
Li et al. reviewed 256 studies worldwide on the effects of lockdowns on older people, children/students, low-income populations, migrant workers, people in prison, people with disabilities, sex workers, victims of domestic violence, refugees, ethnic minorities and people from sexual and gender minorities and summarised their findings:
We show that prolonged loneliness, mental distress, unemployment, income loss, food insecurity, widened inequality and disruption of access to social support and health services were unintended consequences of physical distancing that impacted these vulnerable groups and highlight that physical distancing measures exacerbated the vulnerabilities of different vulnerable populations.
We can be sure that increased unemployment and mental stress will increase the burden of illness for years to come.
Townsend and Owens confirmed that Lockdowns Crush Mental Health and Wellbeing in Young People, finding that the experience of depression among young people during lockdowns was 55% higher than before the pandemic.
Robertson et al. examined the effect of reduced maternal and child health interventions and found:
Our least severe scenario (coverage reductions of 9.8–18.5% and wasting increase of 10%) over six months would result in 253,500 additional child deaths and 12,200 additional maternal deaths. Our most severe scenario (coverage reductions of 39.3–51.9% and wasting increase of 50%) over six months would result in 1,157,000 additional child deaths and 56,700 additional maternal deaths.
There were dire warnings that COVID-19 would cut swathes through the population of the Indian slums, where people live on top of each other. Malan et al. found that 54% of the population in the slums of Mumbai tested positive, as compared with 16.1% in the ‘non-slums’. But they also found that the infection fatality rate in the slums was only 0.076% as compared with 0.263% in the non-slums.
This throws the whole social distancing hypothesis to the ground. The slum-dwellers had lower mortality than their more well-off neighbours. The authors comment drily: “This stark variation in prevalence within wards also highlights the importance of geographic variation for epidemiological modelling and policy discussions of herd immunity.” Indeed, perhaps if we want a population to get to herd immunity as quickly as possible, we should herd them all together, not keep them apart!
The slum-dwellers were the lucky ones – the Indian lockdowns and associated panic thrust untold numbers of others out of the cities and back to their home villages. As Jesline et al. comment: “The concept of social distancing bears no meaning for the migrants because of the persistence of even more pressing and nagging problems of insecurity and hunger.”
These papers make it evident that the poor endured multiple traumas and risks, and there is little reason to believe that they benefited.
What happened in rich countries?
Here is a graph from the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) showing all-cause and excess mortality over the period of six years until late 2020 in my home state of Victoria:

There are two striking features in this figure.
First, the 2020 peak was slightly lower than the peak of the 2017 influenza epidemic. But 2020 was meant to be the first wave of a once-in-a-hundred years pandemic comparable to the influenza pandemic of 1918. Yet 2020 all-cause mortality looks to be merely at the top of the expected range.
Second, the epidemic curve bears no relationship to what was predicted by the ICL or local modelling. There is no sign of the curve being flattened, although Melbourne had the world’s longest (cumulative) lockdown. In fact, the curve is actually sharper than the one in 2017. The modelling is comparative, so you would expect that the comparison between the ‘do nothing’ curve and the intervention curve would be transferable across locations, if the theoretical assumptions have any validity. The Victorian epidemic curve looks like the ‘do nothing’ curve, despite the harshest interventions ever attempted.
We can also benchmark against the neighbouring state of New South Wales. The graphs and tables here show that New South Wales had lower excess deaths in each year of the pandemic, despite taking a more cautious approach to lockdowns. They also show that excess mortality in Australia overall increased in 2021 and 2022 as Government interventions went further. Now 2021 was the year of ‘vaccination +’ (both lockdowns and vaccinations), while in 2022 governments backed off from lockdowns and relied only on vaccination. Mortality increased again.
Case studies of island nations which were relatively isolated during the lockdowns are useful. For example, Iceland also had a more cautious approach compared with New Zealand, following a mitigation strategy instead of New Zealand’s pursuit of elimination. Local experts who are making their case out to the New Zealand COVID-19 inquiry opine: “Iceland’s success at keeping Covid cases and deaths relatively low without the use of stringent restrictions led to the question of whether New Zealand could have achieved similar results without a border closure and lockdowns.” Inevitably they fall back on their modelling to argue that New Zealand could have achieved better outcomes if it had imposed lockdowns earlier, even though New Zealand went hard only four days after the pandemic was declared on March 11th 2020.
So, the push is on to impose lockdowns the same day as a pandemic is declared (preferably earlier!), at a time when nothing is known about its characteristics and relevant risk factors. And this will again be done on the basis of modelling, which is not evidence.
The lockdown hypothesis is not falsifiable, it seems. Whatever the empirical outcomes, the experts prescribe more lockdowns. But most COVID-19 inquiries will accept the need for lockdowns to be imposed more quickly. This will only lead to governments being trigger-happy and taking action too early over outbreaks that do not spread so much.
The Scottish COVID-19 inquiry took a ‘novel’ approach by commissioning a review of the evidence within the framework of evidence-based medicine, which discriminates between types of evidence, some of which are more reliable than others. Most of the academic papers that find in favour of the interventions are based on ‘observational’ studies, which are prone to bias arising from the relatively uncontrolled population samples they select, rather than the more reliable and highly-rated randomised controlled studies (RCTs).
Dr. Croft’s report is rigorous and systematic. The overall findings:
- In 2020 there was scientific evidence to support the use of some of the physical measures (e.g. frequent handwashing, the use of PPE in hospital settings) adopted against COVID-19.
- For other measures (e.g. face mask mandates outside of healthcare settings, lockdowns, social distancing, test, trace and isolate measures) there was either insufficient evidence in 2020 to support their use – or alternatively, no evidence; the evidence base has not changed materially in the intervening three years.
- It has been argued that the restrictive measures introduced during the COVID-19 pandemic resulted in individual, societal and economic harm that was avoidable and that should not have occurred.
- It remains unclear as to whether or not COVID-19 vaccination has resulted in fewer deaths from COVID-19.
The world’s governments embarked on a grand experiment in March 2020, deploying harsh and untried measures on whole populations, without any evidence or insufficient evidence that they would succeed. The idea that total lockdowns would lead to better outcomes was a hypothesis, a hypothesis that needed to be tested before it was deployed in a population at large. Governments should have commissioned RCTs to test the hypotheses that lockdowns and the other non-pharmaceutical interventions would improve overall outcomes. They never did so.
RCTs were conducted for the vaccines, but only a few months of data were collected before they were unblinded and governments started authorising and even mandating the vaccines. This was well before a complete picture of their adverse effects could emerge. And the trials did not establish that the vaccines could save lives, or even ‘slow the spread’.
But Fraiman et al. analysed the data from the mRNA trials of both the Pfizer and the Moderna vaccines and found that: “Combined, there was a 16% higher risk of serious adverse events in mRNA vaccine recipients.” They called for “formal harm-benefit analyses” to be undertaken, but this fell on deaf ears. The vaccine RCTs fell far short of best practice, and governments should have recognised their limitations when framing policy.
The need to undertake rigorous and probing trials of unproven interventions is the basis of medical research ethics, which I am conscious of as the Chair of the Human Research Ethics Committee of a small medical institute. The Nuremberg Code requires that participants in an experiment, the outcome of which is unknown, must give their voluntary consent with full knowledge of the possible risks. This never happened. Also “the experiment should be so conducted as to avoid all unnecessary physical and mental suffering and injury.” Insufficient or no consideration was given to minimising suffering. These principles are amplified in the Helsinki Declaration.
The defence would argue that the threat was so great, governments could not wait to conduct RCTs. But without RCTS, they did not know (and still do not know) whether the benefits outweigh the costs. It is not justifiable in a public health emergency to deploy measures with massive adverse effects on the grounds that they might work in theory, or in virtual reality (modelling). Ioannidis and colleagues have put forward forceful critiques of forecasting and modelling here and here (“Effect estimates of COVID-19 non-pharmaceutical interventions are non-robust and highly model-dependent.”).
The strategies must pass the legal test of necessity. A harsher measure should not be deployed if a more moderate measure would work as well. Indeed, this is written into the Victorian public health legislation. But Bendavid et al. analysed the data from 10 countries and found that harsher measures did not have any significant beneficial effect on case growth compared to more moderate measures.
Governments must select the least harmful measures that can reasonably be expected to achieve the desired outcome overall, which should be lowering excess deaths not just in the short term, but in the medium and long term. And lowering deaths from one particular illness is not defensible if it might increase deaths from other illnesses, for example through deferred health and medical appointments during lockdowns resulting in serious health conditions not being picked up early enough.
In embarking on this grand experiment governments had no idea what they were doing. They recklessly breached all known codes of medical ethics and the principle of necessity apparently without even considering them. They did not consider other tenable strategies such as allowing herd immunity to spread in the younger age groups while focussing on protecting the older age groups. Multiple red flags were thrown up, but governments drove straight past them and simply ignored any evidence of harms and failed to make any attempt to optimise the policies and minimise harms as much as possible. This represents the greatest failure of public health ethics in recorded history.
This is no conspiracy theory. My working hypothesis is that everyone concerned thought they were doing the right thing. But the charge of criminal negligence should be considered given the huge numbers of people who have suffered adverse effects from these measures unnecessarily and out of all proportion to their risk from COVID-19.
Michael Tomlinson is a Higher Education Governance and Quality Consultant. He was formerly Director of the Assurance Group at Australia’s Tertiary Education Quality and Standards Agency, where he led teams to conduct assessments of all registered providers of higher education (including all of Australia’s universities) against the Higher Education Threshold Standards. Before that, for twenty years he held senior positions in Australian universities. He has been an expert panel member for a number of offshore reviews of universities in the Asia-Pacific region. Dr Tomlinson is a Fellow of the Governance Institute of Australia and of the (international) Chartered Governance Institute.
This piece was first published by the Brownstone Institute.
To join in with the discussion please make a donation to The Daily Sceptic.
Profanity and abuse will be removed and may lead to a permanent ban.
I think you have to weight the cost of a life in favour of the young. Any other approach seems unnatural.
Any analysis that doesn’t include a notional cost of lost liberty on the cost side is severely lacking. Governments pay people compensation for wrongful imprisonment.
LOCKDOWN DON’T Work – they kill old people they don’t save old people
Mask don’t work
Where Are the Scientific Studies for Universal Masking?
Why Masks Are a Charade Analysis by Dr. Joseph Mercola
https://articles.mercola.com/sites/articles/archive/2021/08/23/masks-are-charade.aspx?ui=1fb065e0c4152b58bd4ed94cf29c7cbfad40307fb723460ddabacd55f3c58b0c&sd=20210518&cid_source=dnl&cid_medium=email&cid_content=art1HL&cid=20210823&mid=DM965507&rid=1242686923
Stand in South Hill Park Bracknell every Sunday from 10am meet fellow anti lockdown freedom lovers, keep yourself sane, make new friends and have a laugh.
(also Wednesdays from 2pm)
Join our Stand in the Park – Bracknell – Telegram Group
http://t.me/astandintheparkbracknell
Ouch! I’m hoping that the Daily Sceptic looks with disfavor at the citing of dens of kookery like mercola.com
Yes, there’s a reason they used to say women and children first. Of course that doesn’t mean the old don’t matter or that we should euthanise them. But any adult who puts their own life before children’s should be ashamed.
I’m 74. I have 5 granddaughters aged between 22 and 7. Let’s face it, their likely value to society far outweighs mine. They should have been the priority over the last 18 months. I have my degrees and professional qualifications, I have worked but have been retired for years, therefore I do not make an valuable contribution to the national economy. They have had their futures blighted by the over 50s politicians who have also had their chance to learn. I am a drain – they have a productive lfe ahead of them, in spite of the last 18 months. I don’t want to be got rid of, but I am clear headed enough to know that my value is far less than theirs.
Those preferred value numbers still seem ridiculously high – no doubt to try and get the correct answer.
Do they mention the value of someone who will die in the next month covid or no covid?
My guess is we’d soon come to the obvious conclusion without having to conduct a study.
Removed. Rephrased as a top-level comment,
This sort of analysis does very little to convince people one way or the other.
There are so many arbitrary assumptions like the value of each life or the number of people “saved” that if one disagrees with the conclusions one need only take a few shots at the assumptions and retreat back into the comfort of one’s firmly held belief.
What is the assumption about “lives saved” (by shielding measures)? How do these experts determine this estimate? Seems to me the only way you could calculate “lives saved” would be to compare two similar nations that used completely opposite mitigation strategies – One nation did essentially nothing and another did essentially everything. Then you compare the fatalities from COVID.
Unfortunately, we have only one nation – Sweden – in the “placebo” group to perform such “scientific” comparisons. Still, this one comparison does reveal that there is no statistically significant difference in deaths in Sweden to most of the other countries that did use all the lockdown measures, especially when you look at the age cohorts before retirement age.
In America, one could compare mortality data from Alabama – which had much more stringent mitigation mandates – than its neighboring state of Florida. Florida has better mortality statistics on a per capita basis than Alabama. And Florida has more elderly citizens than any state in the union except maybe California.
In other words, more lives were seemingly “saved” in Florida than in Alabama. But this comparison doesn’t fit the narrative, so we can’t use it, I guess.
https://www.covidchartsquiz.com/state-vs-state
Covid charts quiz. Spot the mask mandates and the lockdowns…
So even better still when you look at age groups
There is no benefit in lockdown because communism has no benefits, mediaeval superstition has no benefits.
Oh dear. Political illiteracy strikes again. What we’ve got ain’t ‘communism’ by any stretch of the imagination.
Lockdown is communist, it is a policy imported from a communist dictatorship that has concentration camps.
No, we don’t have communism.
Communist countries didn’t have communism either.
Some more equal, were they?
No, it’s fascism!
Reminds me of that sketch about comminazis.
The only similarity I see is that neither works.
Both communism and medieval superstition seem to lead away from Liberty and towards our current economic model namely Feudalism (although it’s more stealthily done, even though economic-rent is at at historical high).
There was a story a few years back about Europe’s last feudal society (Sark, I think) coming to an end. Didn’t stay away long, did it?
On the contrary, communism always works, it always succeeds in achieving its goal of destruction for the sake of destruction.
Were any lives ‘saved’. Most commentators, even ‘pro lockdown’ ones seem to say all that happens is the can is kicked further down the road. The impact on overall mortality is minimal at best.
Quite. Given the age and co-morbidity profiles of deaths of/with Covid, the likelihood is that a high proportion of these “saved” people would have died anyway soon, either due to Covid catching up with them or to their existing age/conditions.
We haven’t really saved any lives, which can be verified by looking at the all-cause mortality figures. There is no exceptional about last year in terms of deaths
In a rational world, the latest all cause mortality from Belarus would surely be seen as conclusive (I suppose the BBC didn’t cover it…).
No, of course not. The lives “saved” by lockdowns (which I don’t believe) are more than outweighed by the ones lost by all manner of other conditions, some of which have not yet been able to be calculated (how many suicides, deaths from mental illness, bankruptcy, consistent abuse etc). hese are long term figures, which will not become evident for years.
To the rational mind, it is clear that lockdowns ‘weren’t worth it’. There are simply no significant benefits that can be pinned down, whilst the horrendous costs are plain to see.
But … all these analyses depend on the ‘assumptions’ that are made, and then turned into further assumptions about very dodgy monetary equivalents.
The real problem is that governments in general have made no attempt to analyse the immense obvious penalties of lockdowns against the lack of any claimed and unobvious benefits.
Basically, the exercise is fundamentally flawed.
European COVID-19 Vaccine adverse reactions report.
How’s that line up (in terms of numbers jabbed in the EU vassal states) with the UK’s 1500+ jab victims?
It doesn’t.
I’m convinced our total deaths post-vaccination are too low. At a rough guess, at a minimum it should be at least double, and possibly much higher than that, if we assume only 10% of adverse reactions are recorded.
30 day FB ban for posting this!!!!
The real cost, the human cost, the psychological and spiritual cost, has been incalculable.
People are not numbers or economic units.
Seems to me, we need to make just two observations:
Therefore, the “life cost” of Covid19 is zero and the benefits of the Covid19 response is zero.
Disclaimer: Getting on a bit myself, so I’m heading into the higher-chance end.
I’m 74. My 5 granddaughters matter more in terms of the future than I do. I’ve had my working and academic life, my qualifications, my youth (long, long ago) and it they who should have been prioritised. Blow the emotive response of stupid, politicians and so called experts (who are nothing of the kind) that we mustn’t “kill Granny”. This grandma thinks the young should have been prioritised. I don’t want to die, but I am less valuable than they area and to say otherwise is irrational.
Re: The “lives saved” assumption all we can do is look at the ONE “placebo” nation that did not implement “shielding” measures to save lives or slow spread. This nation of course is Sweden.
In the entire nation of Sweden, fewer than 100 people under the age of 40 have died of COVID.
Sweden has more than 14,000 deaths but the average age of a COVID victim is 82.
Apparently, FEWER people under 70 died in Sweden than in nations that went all in on lockdowns. So one could validly argue that no lives were “saved” by the mitigation mandates.
Yes, the benefit side looks to be zero or negative. I’d say it’s very hard to prove to any reasonable degree there was any benefit, so the assumption is that it was zero. The cost side is easier in that whatever approach you take, it’s going to be massive. In truth, the calculation can be done on the back of a postage stamp.
The economic value of a life is assigned and adjusted according to age. Reid’s calculation considers deaths in terms of economic loss. But might not the creeps behind this scam, have looked at the vulnerable (very old, frail, obese) and seen a value to be gained from their deaths?
So even as a decaying old bat I am worth 1.5 million dollars?lHow much does thirty pieces of silver go into 1.5 million dollars?
In my opinion, doing a cost-benefit analysis of lockdowns is fundamentally misguided because it implicitly accepts the assumption the people are essentially the same as cattle, hence, manageing them in them same way is principally ok and the only question here is whether or nor a particular attempt at manageing peoplecattle was efficient.
I’m not a cow. I object to being treated as such. In particular,
I could continue this list, but these are the three most important points which came to my mind.
Meanwhile: in the Philippines, draconian lockdowns continue.
https://mailchi.mp/tomwoods/goodbadnews?e=8e86beb5bb
“due to the so-called “delta” variant, citizens are expected to remain at home for two weeks (a tired trope by now) and may only exit their residences for essential items with a quarantine pass (one per household). Outdoor exercise was allowed until yesterday, but the authorities probably got spooked into banning it when they saw people still outside enjoying themselves (or trying to be healthy) and not cowering in fear at home.”
In New Zealand, lockdowns have been extended. Parliament suspended. Dissidents rounded up, or getting visits from the police for “re-education”, and Jacinda Ardern has sent $3million to the Taliban.
https://m.youtube.com/watch?v=tb0uDUGU50Y
In Australia, there have been large public protests, and the police have used pepper spray and rubber bullets in response.
https://m.youtube.com/watch?v=bD5-1Z1LXeU
Truckers in Australia are planning to bring Australia to a halt, telling people to stock up on food for at least two weeks.
Would anyone have believed this back in 2019??
Bears. Woods. Popes. Catholics. Fictional Detectives and Excrement. FIGHT. BACK. BETTER. Useful information, links and resources: https://www.LCAHub.org/
2 million lives saved by lockdowns? I don’t see how this can possibly be credible, looking at all cause mortality from Belarus. No lockdowns, no restrictions, no disaster.
Lockdowns were worth it. Not to me or society as a whole. The elite has achieved exactly what they wanted…fear and control. It was planned and they probably can’t believe how stupid and compliant society actually is…and how easy it was to achieve their aim.
In the UK government’s document “The tolerability of risk from nuclear power stations” first published by the HSE in 1988 (last revised 1992) there is a UK government department estimated value put on a human life:
“The Department of Transport’s consultation exercise secured widespread endorsement for its proposed value of life for application in road transport appraisal. This value now stands at £660 000 for a life.”
Adjusted for inflation 1992 to 2021 yields £1,320,000 ($1,810,000). This is less than one quarter the estimate of $7.8 million used in the study by L. Jan Reid.
Well, d’uh!